IBJOpinion

TABLER: Market is driving trend toward 'public health'

Back to TopCommentsE-mailPrintBookmark and Share

voices-tabler-norman.jpgThe movement toward a “public health” model may be the most important current trend in American health care. Because the trend is more a result of market forces than of the Affordable Care Act, repealing Obamacare won’t stop it.

Traditionally, American health care was delivered in a highly individualistic manner. An individual chose his physician and arranged payment. Even Medicare and Medicaid patients chose their own physicians. Traditionally, physicians had no legal connection to the hospitals where they practiced.

Although we take this model for granted, it is something of an anomaly. It differs from the approach of other industrialized nations. It differs from our approach to other fundamental needs. We don’t allow citizens to choose their own police officers or firefighters. We address these on a community-wide basis.

What are the signs of this change? One is vocabulary. The ACA uses the term accountable care organization—an entity combining separate components of delivery. So, health care will be delivered by a single entity rather than unrelated components: one-stop shopping.

This concept of integrated delivery had traction well before the Affordable Care Act. Health systems, insurers and employers recognized that the cost of the old system was unaffordable.

Another term is “population.” Under the ACA, health systems are judged—and paid—on the basis of the health of “populations.” Effectiveness (quality) and efficiency (quality compared to cost) are judged by population-wide results.

The term “patient” has declined in favor of “member.” Traditionally, anyone interacting with the health industry was a patient because people interacted with the industry only after illness or injury.

The new theory is that a system is responsible for the health of the members of a population, not just the sick or injured. In the Platonic ideal, no member would be a patient, except maybe for an annual physical or an uncomplicated birth.

What about cost? Cost, or the rate of increase, will probably decline because of the trend away from paying providers for doing things (“fee-for-service”) and because it’s less expensive to maintain health than to address illness or injury after it occurs—like the cost of regular auto maintenance versus repairs after a breakdown.

What else does this trend mean? Choice will be more limited. We will interact with systems rather than choosing among various components. Shopping at a department store is more efficient than shopping at specialty stores (less travel, less time), but it provides less choice.

While limiting individual choice, the trend increases individual responsibility. It encourages us to maintain our health. We will be rewarded for accepting more responsibility, just as insurers reward us for safe driving.

How about quality? The jury is still out, but logic dictates that if providers work together rather than separately and manage health rather than react to illness and injury, quality will improve.

Will there be losers? Yes, people who don’t make an effort to maintain their health may have to pay more—like unsafe drivers.

More controversially, delivery of care in some cases may become more limited. Traditionally, we let a person decide how much care to consume. This is not the approach we take to other basic needs. We don’t give a citizen all the police and fire service he wants.

Of course, a person with the desire and the means can hire private security or fire protection, and that person will be able to buy unlimited health care. But such examples will not be representative.

Losers will also include providers depending on a high volume of expensive procedures. Why?

First, fee-for-service is disappearing.

Second, we’re moving toward payment of a flat amount per person.

Third, many effective methods of maintaining health are inexpensive, such as smarter eating, regular exercise and not smoking.

Fourth, we’re moving to a system that limits health care costs to a budget, as we have long done with other services.

Are these limitations a bad thing? In some ways, yes, because choice is good.

But choice was already limited under the old system. Choice depended on financial means: no means, no choice. Choice also depended on availability. Availability was determined by providers’ individually deciding whether to practice in a particular area.

In the long run, making health care decisions on a community-wide basis might actually increase overall choice, along with overall community health.•

__________

Tabler, an attorney with Faegre Baker Daniels, was formerly the longtime general counsel of Indiana University Health. Views expressed here are the writer’s.

ADVERTISEMENT

Post a comment to this story

COMMENTS POLICY
We reserve the right to remove any post that we feel is obscene, profane, vulgar, racist, sexually explicit, abusive, or hateful.
 
You are legally responsible for what you post and your anonymity is not guaranteed.
 
Posts that insult, defame, threaten, harass or abuse other readers or people mentioned in IBJ editorial content are also subject to removal. Please respect the privacy of individuals and refrain from posting personal information.
 
No solicitations, spamming or advertisements are allowed. Readers may post links to other informational websites that are relevant to the topic at hand, but please do not link to objectionable material.
 
We may remove messages that are unrelated to the topic, encourage illegal activity, use all capital letters or are unreadable.
 

Messages that are flagged by readers as objectionable will be reviewed and may or may not be removed. Please do not flag a post simply because you disagree with it.

Sponsored by
ADVERTISEMENT

facebook - twitter on Facebook & Twitter

Follow on TwitterFollow IBJ on Facebook:
Follow on TwitterFollow IBJ's Tweets on these topics:
 
Subscribe to IBJ
  1. Really, taking someone managing the regulation of Alcohol and making himthe President of an IVY Tech regional campus. Does he have an education background?

  2. Jan, great rant. Now how about you review the report and offer rebuttal of the memo. This might be more conducive to civil discourse than a wild rant with no supporting facts. Perhaps some links to support your assertions would be helpful

  3. I've lived in Indianapolis my whole and been to the track 3 times. Once for a Brickyard, once last year on a practice day for Indy 500, and once when I was a high school student to pick up trash for community service. In the past 11 years, I would say while the IMS is a great venue, there are some upgrades that would show that it's changing with the times, just like the city is. First, take out the bleachers and put in individual seats. Kentucky Motor Speedway has individual seats and they look cool. Fix up the restrooms. Add wi-fi. Like others have suggested, look at bringing in concerts leading up to events. Don't just stick with the country music genre. Pop music would work well too I believe. This will attract more young celebrities to the Indy 500 like the kind that go to the Kentucky Derby. Work with Indy Go to increase the frequency of the bus route to the track during high end events. That way people have other options than worrying about where to park and paying for parking. Then after all of this, look at getting night lights. I think the aforementioned strategies are more necessary than night racing at this point in time.

  4. Talking about congestion ANYWHERE in Indianapolis is absolutely laughable. Sure you may have to wait in 5 minutes of traffic to travel down BR avenue during *peak* times. But that is absolutely nothing compared to actual big cities. Indy is way too suburban to have actual congestion problems. So please, never bring up "congestion" as an excuse to avoid development in Indianapolis. If anything, we could use a little more.

  5. Oh wait. Never mind.

ADVERTISEMENT